Heroes of Economics
Nobel Prizes 1969 - 2003 In 2002 the Prize was awarded to the experimental economist Vernon L. Smith! select a year
|
|
1969 |
Ragnar Frisch Jan Tinbergen |
"For having developed and applied dynamic models for the analysis of economic processes." | |
1970 |
Paul Samuelson |
"For the scientific work through which he has developed static and dynamic economic theory and actively contributed to raising the level of analysis in economic science." | |
1971 |
Simon Kuznets |
"For his empirically founded interpretation of economic growth which has led to new and deepened insight into the economic and social structure and process of development." | |
1972 |
John Hicks Kenneth Arrow |
"For their pioneering contributions to general economic equilibrium theory and welfare theory." | |
1973 |
Wassily Leontief |
"For the development of the input-output method and for its application to important economic problems." | |
1974 |
Gunnar Myrdal Friederich v. Hayek |
"For their pioneering work in the theory of money and economic fluctuations and for their penetrating analysis of the interdependence of economic, social, and institutional phenomena." | |
1975 |
Leonid Kantovarich Tjalling Koopmans |
"For their contributions to the theory of the optimum allocation of resources." | |
1976 |
Milton Friedman |
"For his achievements in the field of consumption analysis, monetary history and theory and for his demonstration of the complexity of stabilisation policy." | |
1977 |
Bertil Ohlin James Meade |
"For their pathbreaking contribution to the theory of international trade and international capital movements." | |
1978 |
Herbert Simon |
"For his pioneering research into the decision making process within economic organisations." | |
1979 |
Theodore Schultz Arthur Lewis |
"For their pioneering research into economic development, with particular consideration of the problems of developing countries." | |
1980 |
Lawrence Klein |
"For the creation of econometric models and their application to the analysis of economic fluctuations and economic policies." | |
1981 |
James Tobin |
"For his analysis of financial markets and their relations to expenditure decisions, employment, production and prices." | |
1982 |
George Stigler |
"For his seminal studies of industrial structure, functioning of markets and causes and effects of public regulation." | |
1983 |
Gerard Debreu |
"For having incorporated new analytic methods into economic theory and for his rigorous reformulation of the theory of general equilibrium." | |
1984 |
Richard Stone |
"For having made fundamental contributions to the development of systems of national accounts and hence greatly improved the basis for empirical economic analysis." | |
1985 |
Franco Modigliani |
"For his pioneering analysis of savings and financial markets." | |
1986 |
James Buchanan |
"For his development of the contractual and constitutional bases of the theory of economic and political decision making." | |
1987 |
Robert Solow |
"For his contributions to the theory of economic growth." | |
1988 |
Maurice Allais |
"For his pioneering contributions to the theory of markets and efficient utilisation of resources." | |
1989 |
Trygve Haavelmo |
"For his clarification of the probability theory foundation of econometrics and his analysis of simultaneous economic structures." | |
1990 |
Harry Markowitz Merton Miller |
William Sharpe |
|
"For their pioneering work in the theory of financial economics" | |
1991 |
Ronald Coase |
"For his discovery and clarification of the significance of transaction costs and property rights for the traditional structure and functioning of the economy." | |
1992 |
Gary Becker |
"For having extended the domain of microeconomic analysis to a wide range of human behaviour and interaction, including non-market behaviour." | |
1993 |
Robert Fogel Douglass North |
"For having renewed research in economic history by applying economic theory and quantitative methods to explain economic and institutional change." | |
1994 |
John Harsanyi John Nash |
Reinhard Selten |
|
"For their pioneering analysis of equilibria in the theory of non-cooperative games." | |
1995 |
Robert Lucas |
"For having developed and applied the hypothesis of rational expectations, and thereby having transformed macroeconomic analysis and deepened our understanding of economic policy." | |
1996 |
James Mirrlees William Vickrey |
"For their fundamental contributions to the economic theory of incentives under asymmetric information." | |
1997 |
Robert C. Merton Myron S. Scholes |
"For a new method to determine the value of derivatives" | |
1998 |
Amartya Sen |
"For his contributions to welfare economics." | |
1999 |
Robert A. Mundell |
"For his analysis of monetary and fiscal policy under different exchange rate regimes and his analysis of optimum currency areas." | |
2000 |
James Heckman Daniel McFadden |
"To James Heckman for his development of theory and methods for analyzing selective samples and to Daniel McFadden for his development of theory and methods for analyzing discrete choice." | |
2001 |
George A. Akerlof A. Michael Spence |
Joseph E. Stiglitz |
|
"For their analyses of markets with asymmetric information." | |
2002 |
Daniel Kahneman Vernon L. Smith |
"To Kahneman for having integrated insights from psychological research into economic science, especially concerning human judgment and decision-making under uncertainty and to Smith for having established laboratory experiments as a tool in empirical economic analysis, especially in the study of alternative market mechanisms" | |
2003 |
|
“To Engle for methods of analyzing economic time
series with time-varying volatility (ARCH) and to Granger for methods
of analyzing economic time series with common trends (cointegration)”.
|
|
Some guys who never made it to the Nobel Prize
(well, they never really had the chance...)
...it's the same reason why he never got tenure at the university!
...his first subjects were named Adam and Eve! |
page by Tilman Slembeck - 9 October 2002 - updated 10/2003